Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  251 /342 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 251 /342 Next Page
Page Background

臺大管理論叢

27

卷第

2S

251

incentives to reduce risk resulting in purchasing more reinsurance based on managerial

professional quality than routine new CEOs.

On the one hand, insurers with non-routine CEO turnover tend to purchase more

reinsurance than insurers with routine CEO turnover because new CEOs resulting from

routine turnover are from the board and they are familiar with the direction of the board. In

addition, if the new CEO is promoted through routine turnover, she/he should be better

trusted than non-routine CEO. Routine-turnover CEOs have worked with other directors in

the past. If routine-turnover CEOs maintain the current reinsurance policy and unexpected

huge losses occur, the board members are more likely to attribute the losses as unexpected

losses rather than poor reinsurance decisions. New non-routine CEOs may want to purchase

more reinsurance to transfer their firms’ risk. When huge losses occur, non-routine turnover

CEOs are more likely to be blamed for insufficient reinsurance because they have yet to

establish their credibility with the board.

On the other hand, insurers with non-routine CEO turnover are more likely to take more

risk and thus purchase less reinsurance. The reason is that non-routine CEO turnover are

generally involved with certain negative events of insurers (e.g., termination of old CEOs

because of poor performance). Goel and Thakor (2008) suggest that the board’s decision to

retain or fire a CEO is based on his/her observed performance. The board is more likely to

tolerate new CEOs appointed as a result of non-routine CEO turnover that failed a high risk

project than CEOs who have been with the insurers for a while. The two conflicting

arguments above lead to the following null hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2: The reinsurance decision of insurers with routine or non-routine CEO

turnover is not different from that of insurers without CEO turnover

after CEO turnover.

2.3 Forced CEO Turnover, Voluntary CEO Turnover and Reinsurance Demand

Voluntary CEO turnover can emerge from normal CEO turnover (i.e., health,

retirement, or death). However, no evidence of a significant relation between voluntary CEO

turnover and prior corporate activities or performance has been obtained (e.g., Huson et al.,

2001; Huson, Malatesta, and Parrino, 2004). In contrast, forced CEO turnovers may be

associated with poor prior performance (e.g., DeFond and Park, 1999). Čihák et al. (2009)

find that a significantly positive relation between a forced executive (i.e., president,

chairperson, CEO and COO) turnover and higher default risk, because the executive’s

exposure to be forced out job risk. Huson et al. (2004) find that top management turnover