Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  250 /302 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 250 /302 Next Page
Page Background

顧客與供應商關係與成本結構

250

demand shocks.

4

Using employment protection legislation (EPL) provisions in 19 OECD

countries as a proxy for larger labor adjustment costs, Banker et al. (2013) find that firms

in these countries exhibit greater cost stickiness.

Anderson et al. (2003) document that cost stickiness declines with the aggregation of

periods since managers better assess the permanence of a change in demand and the

adjustment costs become smaller than the cost of retaining unutilized resources. Chen et

al. (2012) document that a lower degree of SG&A cost stickiness in firms experiencing

negative demand shocks in two consecutive years as managers are more likely to consider

fall in demand to be permanent when sales decrease in two consecutive years and

downsize the capacity accordingly.

In addition, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom (2004) extend Anderson et al.

(2003) and find that capacity utilization may affect the manager's response to a change in

activity levels. They argue that manager’s response to a decrease in activity levels is

smaller (larger) than that for an increase only when capacity is currently strained (in

excess).

2.1.1.2 Agency Explanations

Some studies attribute cost stickiness behaviors in part to agency problem. For

example, based on the empire building and the downsizing literature, Chen et al. (2012)

argue that managers’ incentives to grow a firm beyond its optimal size or to maintain

unutilized resources for their personal benefit induce cost stickiness. Using corporate free

cash flow, chief executive officer (CEO) horizon, tenure, and compensation structure as

proxies for agency problems. They find that the degree of cost stickiness is positively

associated with agency problem, and the effective corporate governance can mitigate such

positive association.

On the other hand, Kama and Weiss (2013) find that managers are more likely to cut

down on slack resources for sales decreases when they have incentives to avoid losses or

earning decreases, or to meet analyst earnings forecasts. Such managerial incentives

significantly moderate the degree of cost stickiness. Likewise, using a sample of private

Belgium firms, Dierynck et al. (2012) find that firms that just meet or beat the zero

earnings benchmark exhibit less labor cost asymmetry when facing sales decreases in

relative to other firms.

4 Balakrishnan et al. (2014) suggest that in Anderson’s model, changes in cost should be scaled by sales

rather than total costs in order to control for the effects of fixed costs.